In this paper, bankster reputation as a coordination mechanism (“focal arbitrator”) in the game of interest rate manipulation and the effects of punishment will be analyzed with the aid of game-theoretical instruments. In such a game with multiple equilibria, the “bad” to-manipulate equilibrium arises because of “bankster expectations”. Under this condition, the game can, in the short term, only be changed through penalties so that the not-to-manipulate strategy becomes the dominant one. Should it happen that the bankster reputation be destroyed in the long term, penalties would, once again, become superfluous, because the “good” not-to-manipulate equilibrium would appear even in self-interested actions, due to the good banker expectations.
Published in | International Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences (Volume 1, Issue 1) |
DOI | 10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13 |
Page(s) | 21-24 |
Creative Commons |
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, provided the original work is properly cited. |
Copyright |
Copyright © The Author(s), 2013. Published by Science Publishing Group |
LIBOR, Interest Rate Manipulation, Game Theory, Focal Point, Banksters
[1] | Snider, Connan and Thomas Youle (2009), Diagnosing the LIBOR: Strategic Manipulation and Member Portfolio Positions, Working Paper (unpublished). |
[2] | Abrantes-Metz, Rosa M. et al. (2009), „Libor manipulation?", Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (1), 136–150. |
[3] | Ellis, David M. (2011), LIBOR Manipulation: A Brief Overview of the Debate, FTI UK London. |
[4] | Siedenbiedel, Christian (2013), "Die Libor-Bande", Frankfurter Allgemeine Sonntagszeitung, No. 21, 21-22. |
[5] | Maisch, Michael (2013), "Der Libor ist ein Auslaufmodell", Handelsblatt, No. 10, 26. |
[6] | Economist (2012), "Banksters", The Economist 404 (8792), 14. |
[7] | Holler, Manfred J. and Gerhard Illing (2006), Einführung in die Spieltheorie, 6th ed., Springer, Berlin et al. |
[8] | Myerson, Roger B. (1992), Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict, Harvard University Press, Cambridge and London. |
[9] | Schelling, Thomas C. (2010), "Game Theory: A Practitioner’s Approach", Economics and Philosophy 26 (1), 27-46. |
[10] | Popper, Karl R. (2006), "Wie ich die Philosophie sehe", in: Popper, K. R., Alle Menschen sind Philosophen, 6th ed., Piper Verlag, München, 11-22. |
[11] | Rubinstein, Ariel (1991), "Comments on the Interpretation of Game Theory", Econometrica 59 (4), 909-924. |
[12] | Haaker, Andreas (2012), Zur Manipulation von Referenzzinssätzen: Versuch einer einfachen spieltheoretischen Analyse des Grundproblems, Working Paper, Berlin (unpublished). |
[13] | Böll, Sven et al. (2012), "Das Kartell", Der Spiegel, No. 31, 64-70. |
[14] | Coase, Ronald H. (1960), "The Problem of Social Cost", Journal of Law and Economics 3 (Oct.), 1-44. |
[15] | Schelling, Thomas C. (1960 [1980]), The Strategy of Conflict, Harvard University Press, Cambridge and London. |
[16] | Myerson, Roger B. (2009), "Learning from Schelling’s Strategy of Conflict", Journal of Economic Literature 47 (4), 1109-1125. |
[17] | Kirchgässner, Gebhard (2008), Homo Oeconomicus, 3rd ed., Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen. |
[18] | Harsanyi, John C. and Reinhard Selten (1988 [1992]), A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games, The MIT Press, Cambridge and London. |
[19] | Binmore, Ken (2007), Game Theory, Oxford University Press, New York. |
[20] | Dixit, Avinash K. and Barry J. Nalebuff, (2010), The Art of Strategy, W. W. Norton & Company, New York and London. |
[21] | Ludwig, Thomas (2012), "EU zeigt keine Toleranz für Zinsmanipulationen", Handelsblatt, No. 143, 27. |
[22] | Hurwicz, Leonid (2008), "But Who Will Guard the Guardians?", American Economic Review 98 (3), 577-585. |
[23] | Arnold, Volker (2009), "Vom Sollen zum Wollen – über neuere Entwicklungen in der Wirtschaftsordnung", Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 10 (3), 253-265. |
[24] | Maisch, Michael (2013), "Blick zurück im Zorn", Handelsblatt, No. 30, 27. |
[25] | The Wheatley Review (2012), The Wheatley Review of LIBOR: final report, September 2012. |
APA Style
Andreas Haaker. (2013). To Manipulate or Not to Manipulate – A Short Comment on the Game of Interest Rate Manipulation. International Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences, 1(1), 21-24. https://doi.org/10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13
ACS Style
Andreas Haaker. To Manipulate or Not to Manipulate – A Short Comment on the Game of Interest Rate Manipulation. Int. J. Econ. Finance Manag. Sci. 2013, 1(1), 21-24. doi: 10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13
AMA Style
Andreas Haaker. To Manipulate or Not to Manipulate – A Short Comment on the Game of Interest Rate Manipulation. Int J Econ Finance Manag Sci. 2013;1(1):21-24. doi: 10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13
@article{10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13, author = {Andreas Haaker}, title = {To Manipulate or Not to Manipulate – A Short Comment on the Game of Interest Rate Manipulation}, journal = {International Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences}, volume = {1}, number = {1}, pages = {21-24}, doi = {10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13}, url = {https://doi.org/10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13}, eprint = {https://article.sciencepublishinggroup.com/pdf/10.11648.j.ijefm.20130101.13}, abstract = {In this paper, bankster reputation as a coordination mechanism (“focal arbitrator”) in the game of interest rate manipulation and the effects of punishment will be analyzed with the aid of game-theoretical instruments. In such a game with multiple equilibria, the “bad” to-manipulate equilibrium arises because of “bankster expectations”. Under this condition, the game can, in the short term, only be changed through penalties so that the not-to-manipulate strategy becomes the dominant one. Should it happen that the bankster reputation be destroyed in the long term, penalties would, once again, become superfluous, because the “good” not-to-manipulate equilibrium would appear even in self-interested actions, due to the good banker expectations.}, year = {2013} }
TY - JOUR T1 - To Manipulate or Not to Manipulate – A Short Comment on the Game of Interest Rate Manipulation AU - Andreas Haaker Y1 - 2013/02/20 PY - 2013 N1 - https://doi.org/10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13 DO - 10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13 T2 - International Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences JF - International Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences JO - International Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences SP - 21 EP - 24 PB - Science Publishing Group SN - 2326-9561 UR - https://doi.org/10.11648/j.ijefm.20130101.13 AB - In this paper, bankster reputation as a coordination mechanism (“focal arbitrator”) in the game of interest rate manipulation and the effects of punishment will be analyzed with the aid of game-theoretical instruments. In such a game with multiple equilibria, the “bad” to-manipulate equilibrium arises because of “bankster expectations”. Under this condition, the game can, in the short term, only be changed through penalties so that the not-to-manipulate strategy becomes the dominant one. Should it happen that the bankster reputation be destroyed in the long term, penalties would, once again, become superfluous, because the “good” not-to-manipulate equilibrium would appear even in self-interested actions, due to the good banker expectations. VL - 1 IS - 1 ER -